TutorChase logo
Login
AP Microeconomics Notes

1.6.3 Marginal Utility per Dollar and Optimal Consumer Choice

Consumers aim to get the most satisfaction possible from their limited income by comparing the benefit gained from each dollar spent on different goods.

Understanding marginal utility per dollar

In a world of limited income and unlimited wants, consumers must make choices about how to spend their money. One of the most important tools they use is the marginal utility per dollar. This concept allows consumers to compare the additional satisfaction they receive from different goods, relative to the amount of money they must spend.

What is marginal utility per dollar?

To understand marginal utility per dollar, we first need to define a few key terms:

  • Marginal utility (MU) is the extra satisfaction or benefit a consumer receives from consuming one more unit of a good or service.

  • Price (P) is the cost of purchasing a single unit of that good or service.

  • Marginal utility per dollar (MU ÷ P) is the amount of utility (satisfaction) gained for each dollar spent on a good.

This ratio allows consumers to compare how efficiently their money is being spent across different goods. A higher marginal utility per dollar means a better deal in terms of satisfaction gained.

Why is marginal utility per dollar important?

Consumers have limited incomes, so they want to get the maximum total utility from their spending. Since different goods provide different levels of satisfaction and have different prices, comparing marginal utility per dollar allows consumers to find the combination of goods that gives them the highest total benefit.

If a consumer is deciding between two goods, the one that provides more marginal utility per dollar is the better choice. This comparison helps guide rational decision-making and leads to a more satisfying allocation of resources.

For example:

  • A slice of pizza gives 20 utils and costs 4.Itsmarginalutilityperdollaris20÷4=<strong>5utilsperdollar</strong>.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Asandwichgives15utilsandcosts4. Its marginal utility per dollar is 20 ÷ 4 = <strong>5 utils per dollar</strong>.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">A sandwich gives 15 utils and costs 2. Its marginal utility per dollar is 15 ÷ 2 = 7.5 utils per dollar.

The sandwich gives more satisfaction per dollar, so the consumer should choose it if their goal is to maximize utility.

The utility-maximizing rule

To make optimal consumption decisions, consumers follow what is called the utility-maximizing rule. This rule explains how to allocate a budget in a way that maximizes total utility across all goods.

Defining the utility-maximizing rule

The utility-maximizing rule states that consumers maximize utility when the marginal utility per dollar is equal across all goods.

In equation form:

MUx ÷ Px = MUy ÷ Py

Where:

  • MUx is the marginal utility of good X

  • Px is the price of good X

  • MUy is the marginal utility of good Y

  • Py is the price of good Y

This rule means that the consumer is getting the same satisfaction from the last dollar spent on each good. If this condition is not met, the consumer can improve their total utility by reallocating their spending.

Why the rule works

Suppose the marginal utility per dollar spent on good X is greater than that of good Y. This means the consumer is getting more satisfaction from X than Y, per dollar spent. To increase total satisfaction, the consumer should buy more of good X and less of good Y.

This reallocation continues until the marginal utility per dollar becomes equal for both goods. At this point, the consumer has no incentive to change their spending pattern, and utility is maximized.

Conditions for optimal consumption

For a consumer to reach an optimal consumption bundle, three conditions must be satisfied:

  • The marginal utility per dollar is equal across all goods the consumer is buying.

  • The entire budget is spent. If the consumer does not use all their available income, utility is not being maximized.

  • Prices and marginal utilities are known and considered when making decisions.

If any of these conditions are not met, the consumer could make a better choice by adjusting their spending.

Step-by-step example of optimal consumer choice

Let’s walk through a step-by-step example without using a table.

Imagine a student has 10</strong>tospendontwogoods:<strong>granolabars</strong>and<strong>fruitcups</strong>.Thepriceofagranolabaris<strong>10</strong> to spend on two goods: <strong>granola bars</strong> and <strong>fruit cups</strong>. The price of a granola bar is <strong>2, and the price of a fruit cup is 1</strong>.</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Thestudentexperiencesthefollowingmarginalutilities:</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>GranolaBars<br></strong>1stbar=10utils<br>2ndbar=8utils<br>3rdbar=6utils<br>4thbar=4utils<br>5thbar=2utils</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>FruitCups<br></strong>1stcup=6utils<br>2ndcup=5utils<br>3rdcup=4utils<br>4thcup=3utils<br>5thcup=2utils</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Nowcalculatethe<strong>marginalutilityperdollar</strong>foreachunit:</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>GranolaBars<br></strong>1st=10÷2=5<br>2nd=8÷2=4<br>3rd=6÷2=3<br>4th=4÷2=2<br>5th=2÷2=1</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)"><strong>FruitCups<br></strong>1st=6÷1=6<br>2nd=5÷1=5<br>3rd=4÷1=4<br>4th=3÷1=3<br>5th=2÷1=2</span></p><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Thestudentstartsbyspendingmoneyontheitemwiththehighestmarginalutilityperdollar:</span></p><ol><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">1stfruitcup(MU/P=6)1</strong>.</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The student experiences the following marginal utilities:</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Granola Bars<br></strong> 1st bar = 10 utils<br> 2nd bar = 8 utils<br> 3rd bar = 6 utils<br> 4th bar = 4 utils<br> 5th bar = 2 utils</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Fruit Cups<br></strong> 1st cup = 6 utils<br> 2nd cup = 5 utils<br> 3rd cup = 4 utils<br> 4th cup = 3 utils<br> 5th cup = 2 utils</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">Now calculate the <strong>marginal utility per dollar</strong> for each unit:</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Granola Bars<br></strong> 1st = 10 ÷ 2 = 5<br> 2nd = 8 ÷ 2 = 4<br> 3rd = 6 ÷ 2 = 3<br> 4th = 4 ÷ 2 = 2<br> 5th = 2 ÷ 2 = 1</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)"><strong>Fruit Cups<br></strong> 1st = 6 ÷ 1 = 6<br> 2nd = 5 ÷ 1 = 5<br> 3rd = 4 ÷ 1 = 4<br> 4th = 3 ÷ 1 = 3<br> 5th = 2 ÷ 1 = 2</span></p><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">The student starts by spending money on the item with the highest marginal utility per dollar:</span></p><ol><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">1st fruit cup (MU/P = 6) → 1 spent

  • 1st granola bar (MU/P = 5) → 2spent</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">2ndfruitcup(MU/P=5)2 spent</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">2nd fruit cup (MU/P = 5) → 1 spent

  • 2nd granola bar (MU/P = 4) → 2spent</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">3rdfruitcup(MU/P=4)2 spent</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">3rd fruit cup (MU/P = 4) → 1 spent

  • 3rd granola bar (MU/P = 3) → 2spent</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">4thfruitcup(MU/P=3)2 spent</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">4th fruit cup (MU/P = 3) → 1 spent

  • Total spent = 10</span></p><ul><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">3granolabars=10</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">3 granola bars = 6

  • 4 fruit cups = $4

  • At this point, the marginal utility per dollar for both goods is equal: 3 utils per dollar. The consumer has maximized utility by following the utility-maximizing rule.

    Responding to changes in price

    When the price of a good changes, the marginal utility per dollar also changes. Consumers must then adjust their consumption to restore balance between the goods.

    What happens when a price drops?

    If the price of good X falls, the marginal utility per dollar of X rises:

    • MUx ÷ Px increases

    • Now MUx ÷ Px > MUy ÷ Py

    This tells the consumer that good X is now providing more utility per dollar than good Y. To maximize utility, the consumer should buy more of X and less of Y. This process continues until the ratios are equal again.

    This behavior reflects the law of demand: as the price of a good decreases, the quantity demanded increases.

    What happens when a price increases?

    If the price of a good rises, the marginal utility per dollar of that good falls. The consumer now gets less satisfaction for each dollar spent on that good and should reduce consumption of it.

    Again, the consumer shifts spending toward the good with the higher marginal utility per dollar, rebalancing their consumption.

    Visualizing optimal consumption with a graph

    Although marginal utility per dollar is usually calculated with numbers, it can also be represented graphically.

    Budget lines and indifference curves

    • A budget line shows all combinations of two goods that a consumer can buy with their income.

    • An indifference curve shows all combinations of two goods that provide the same total utility.

    The optimal consumption bundle occurs where the budget line is tangent to the highest indifference curve the consumer can reach.

    At this point:

    • The consumer is spending all of their income.

    • The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) between the two goods is equal to the ratio of their prices.

    • In marginal utility terms, this is where MUx ÷ Px = MUy ÷ Py.

    Interpreting the graph

    Imagine a curve that slopes downward and flattens as it moves right (an indifference curve) intersecting a straight downward-sloping line (the budget line). The point of tangency is where the consumer’s satisfaction is maximized, and the utility-maximizing rule is satisfied.

    Misallocation and utility loss

    If a consumer is not following the utility-maximizing rule, they are not making the best use of their income.

    For example:

    • Suppose MUx ÷ Px = 7 and MUy ÷ Py = 4

    • The consumer is getting more utility per dollar from good X

    • To maximize total utility, the consumer should buy more of good X and less of good Y

    This reallocation continues until MUx ÷ Px equals MUy ÷ Py. When consumers ignore this rule, they experience a loss of potential satisfaction, even if they are spending their full budget.

    It's also important to remember that if a good is not being purchased at all, it's likely because its marginal utility per dollar is lower than that of other goods. Consumers only include goods in their bundle if they contribute to maximizing overall utility.

    Understanding and applying the marginal utility per dollar concept helps students see how rational consumers make day-to-day choices about spending. It also provides the foundation for more advanced concepts in microeconomics like demand curves, indifference analysis, and consumer surplus.

    FAQ

    If the marginal utility per dollar is not equal across all goods and the budget is fully spent, the consumer is not maximizing total utility. Even with a fixed income, a consumer can improve satisfaction by reallocating spending. For example, if good A provides 10 utils per dollar and good B provides 5 utils per dollar, the consumer is getting more satisfaction from each dollar spent on good A. To increase total utility, the consumer should reduce consumption of good B and increase consumption of good A. This might mean buying one less unit of good B and using the saved money to purchase an additional unit of good A. Though the total money spent remains unchanged, the utility gained from that money increases. The reallocation should continue until the marginal utility per dollar is equal for both goods. Equalizing these ratios is the key condition for achieving an optimal consumption bundle, even without increasing income.

    Marginal utility per dollar is closely tied to opportunity cost because every dollar spent on one good is a dollar that cannot be spent on another. When a consumer chooses to buy one good over another, they are giving up the utility that could have been gained from the alternative. This forgone utility is the opportunity cost of the decision. To minimize opportunity cost and maximize total utility, consumers compare marginal utility per dollar across all available options. If one good offers a higher marginal utility per dollar, choosing it means giving up less utility than choosing the good with a lower marginal utility per dollar. This comparison allows consumers to allocate resources efficiently. Ignoring marginal utility per dollar could lead to spending that generates lower overall satisfaction and higher opportunity costs. Thus, marginal utility per dollar provides a way for consumers to evaluate trade-offs and make informed decisions that reduce opportunity cost.

    Yes, a consumer can achieve utility maximization even if they purchase only one good, but this typically happens under specific conditions. If a consumer faces a situation where the marginal utility per dollar of one good is consistently higher than all alternatives, and no other combination of goods can match that ratio, then spending the entire budget on that one good is rational and utility-maximizing. This might occur if the consumer has very strong preferences for one particular good or if the prices and marginal utilities of other goods offer significantly lower utility per dollar. However, in most real-world scenarios, diminishing marginal utility causes the marginal utility per dollar of a good to decrease with each additional unit consumed. At some point, the consumer may be better off diversifying consumption to include a second good with a higher marginal utility per dollar. Therefore, maximizing utility with a single good is possible but usually only in very specific or simplified cases.

    Preferences significantly influence marginal utility per dollar, even when prices are constant. A consumer's preferences determine how much satisfaction or utility they derive from consuming additional units of a good. Two consumers facing the same prices may have different marginal utilities for the same goods because they value them differently based on personal tastes, habits, cultural background, or individual needs. For instance, one consumer may gain high utility from chocolate and low utility from fruit, while another may prefer the opposite. Since marginal utility per dollar is calculated by dividing utility by price, a change in preferences alters the numerator of that ratio, impacting consumption decisions. As preferences shift, the marginal utility of goods changes, causing the consumer to reallocate spending to reflect the new utility per dollar ratios. Therefore, even without a price change, adjustments in personal preferences can lead to a new optimal consumption bundle and redefined utility-maximizing choices.

    Indivisible goods, which cannot be bought in fractional units (like cars, smartphones, or furniture), can complicate the strict application of the utility-maximizing rule. The rule assumes that consumers can make fine-tuned adjustments to their consumption, buying partial units if needed to equalize marginal utility per dollar. However, with indivisible goods, consumers must choose whole units, which can prevent exact equality between the marginal utility per dollar of different goods. In such cases, consumers make the best possible allocation that comes as close as possible to satisfying the rule while respecting quantity restrictions. This may mean selecting the bundle where the marginal utility per dollar is nearly equal across goods, even if not perfectly so. Additionally, consumers may need to evaluate utility in broader terms, weighing larger jumps in utility from acquiring an additional whole unit, rather than marginal changes. Despite this limitation, the utility-maximizing principle still guides decision-making in these cases by encouraging the most efficient use of income given the indivisibility constraint.

    Practice Questions

    A consumer has 12tospendontwogoods:applesandbananas.Applescost12 to spend on two goods: apples and bananas. Apples cost 3 each and bananas cost $2 each. The marginal utility of the third apple is 24, and the marginal utility of the fourth banana is 16. Is the consumer maximizing utility? If not, what should they do to increase total utility?

    The consumer is not maximizing utility. To determine optimal consumption, compare the marginal utility per dollar: MU per dollar for the third apple is 24 ÷ 3 = 8, and for the fourth banana it is 16 ÷ 2 = 8. Since both ratios are equal, the consumer is currently maximizing utility at this combination. If, however, the marginal utility per dollar of one good were higher than the other, the consumer could increase total utility by buying more of the good with the higher ratio and less of the other. In this case, no reallocation is necessary since utility per dollar is equal.

    Explain how a consumer uses the utility-maximizing rule to determine the optimal consumption bundle when choosing between two goods, and what happens if the price of one good falls.

    A consumer uses the utility-maximizing rule by comparing the marginal utility per dollar of each good and adjusting spending until MUx ÷ Px equals MUy ÷ Py. This ensures that each dollar spent yields the same additional utility, which maximizes total satisfaction. If the price of one good falls, the marginal utility per dollar of that good increases. The consumer will then purchase more of the now-cheaper good and less of the other good to reestablish equality between the two ratios. This adjustment continues until the consumer reaches a new optimal consumption bundle where utility per dollar is again equal.

    Hire a tutor

    Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

    1/2
    Your details
    Alternatively contact us via
    WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email