TutorChase logo
Login
AP Macroeconomics Notes

1.5.4. Graphical representation of supply curve shifts

Shifts in the supply curve occur when factors other than the price of a good or service change, affecting the quantity supplied at all price levels. These shifts indicate a fundamental change in producers' ability or willingness to produce goods, independent of the good’s price. A shift can either increase or decrease supply, and these changes are represented graphically by movements of the entire supply curve. Understanding these shifts is crucial for analyzing market behaviors and predicting price fluctuations.

Understanding supply curve shifts

Definition of a supply curve shift

A shift in the supply curve occurs when the quantity supplied of a good or service changes at every price level due to external factors. This is different from a movement along the supply curve, which is caused by changes in the price of the good itself.

  • A rightward shift indicates an increase in supply, meaning that at every price level, more of the good is available for sale.

  • A leftward shift indicates a decrease in supply, meaning that at every price level, less of the good is available for sale.

These shifts are represented graphically by drawing a new supply curve either to the right or the left of the original supply curve.

Graphical representation of supply curve shifts

To illustrate a shift in supply, we use multiple supply curves on a standard price-quantity graph. The x-axis represents quantity supplied, while the y-axis represents price. The typical supply curve slopes upward, reflecting the law of supply: higher prices lead to higher quantity supplied, ceteris paribus.

  • Original supply curve (S₀) represents the initial supply conditions.

  • Increase in supply (S₁) shifts the curve rightward.

  • Decrease in supply (S₂) shifts the curve leftward.

This visual representation allows us to analyze how external factors influence market supply at various price points.

Examples of supply shifts

Example 1: Increase in supply

Suppose a new technological advancement in the production of laptops significantly reduces manufacturing costs. Since production becomes cheaper and more efficient, manufacturers can now supply more laptops at every price level.

If the original supply curve (S₀) reflected the following data:

  • At a price of 600,100,000laptopsweresupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Atapriceof600, 100,000 laptops were supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At a price of 800, 150,000 laptops were supplied.

  • At a price of 1000,200,000laptopsweresupplied.</span></p></li></ul><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Aftertheintroductionofnewtechnology,the<strong>supplycurveshiftsrightward(S1)</strong>,leadingto:</span></p><ul><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Atapriceof1000, 200,000 laptops were supplied.</span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">After the introduction of new technology, the <strong>supply curve shifts rightward (S₁)</strong>, leading to:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At a price of 600, 130,000 laptops are now supplied.

  • At a price of 800,190,000laptopsarenowsupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Atapriceof800, 190,000 laptops are now supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At a price of 1000, 250,000 laptops are now supplied.

This shift from S₀ to S₁ represents an increase in supply, as more laptops are available at each price level due to lower production costs.

Example 2: Decrease in supply

Now, suppose the cost of a key input in laptop production, such as semiconductor chips, increases dramatically. This raises overall production costs, leading to fewer laptops being supplied at every price level.

If the original supply curve (S₀) reflected:

  • At a price of 600,100,000laptopsweresupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Atapriceof600, 100,000 laptops were supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At a price of 800, 150,000 laptops were supplied.

  • At a price of 1000,200,000laptopsweresupplied.</span></p></li></ul><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Aftertheincreaseininputcosts,the<strong>supplycurveshiftsleftward(S2)</strong>,leadingto:</span></p><ul><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Atapriceof1000, 200,000 laptops were supplied.</span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">After the increase in input costs, the <strong>supply curve shifts leftward (S₂)</strong>, leading to:</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At a price of 600, only 80,000 laptops are now supplied.

  • At a price of 800,only120,000laptopsarenowsupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Atapriceof800, only 120,000 laptops are now supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">At a price of 1000, only 160,000 laptops are now supplied.

This shift from S₀ to S₂ represents a decrease in supply, as higher production costs lead to reduced availability of laptops at all price levels.

Causes of supply curve shifts

Factors that increase supply (shift rightward)

A rightward shift of the supply curve occurs when producers can supply more of a good at every price level. This can result from:

  • Lower input costs: A decrease in production costs makes goods cheaper to produce, allowing firms to increase supply.

    • Example: A decline in oil prices reduces transportation costs, making it cheaper to distribute goods.

  • Advances in technology: Improvements in production methods increase efficiency, reducing costs and increasing supply.

    • Example: Automation in car manufacturing enables faster production at a lower cost.

  • Government subsidies: When the government provides financial support, production becomes cheaper, leading to higher supply.

    • Example: Subsidies for renewable energy encourage more solar panel production.

  • Entry of new producers: More firms in the market increase overall supply.

    • Example: A rise in smartphone manufacturers leads to more phones being available in the market.

  • Positive producer expectations: If businesses expect future profits to rise, they increase production now.

    • Example: Farmers expecting higher wheat prices may plant more crops in anticipation.

Factors that decrease supply (shift leftward)

A leftward shift of the supply curve occurs when producers supply less of a good at every price level due to rising costs or other constraints.

  • Higher input costs: When costs for raw materials, labor, or energy increase, production becomes more expensive, reducing supply.

    • Example: A rise in steel prices increases car manufacturing costs, reducing supply.

  • Supply chain disruptions: Events that hinder production or transportation can decrease supply.

    • Example: A natural disaster damages coffee farms, leading to a reduced global coffee supply.

  • Government regulations and taxes: Higher taxes or stricter regulations increase production costs, lowering supply.

    • Example: New environmental laws limit oil drilling, reducing oil supply.

  • Exit of firms from the market: If businesses shut down or exit an industry, overall supply declines.

    • Example: The bankruptcy of a major airline reduces available flights.

  • Negative producer expectations: If firms anticipate lower future prices, they might cut back on production now.

    • Example: If oil producers expect a drop in crude oil prices, they may reduce drilling efforts.

Illustrating supply shifts with a numerical example

Consider the market for oranges.

  • Original supply curve (S₀) represents initial conditions.

  • Increase in supply (S₁) occurs when favorable weather boosts crop yields.

  • Decrease in supply (S₂) occurs when a drought reduces harvests.

If at different price levels, the quantity supplied changes as follows:

Original supply (S₀):

  • 1.00perpound50,000orangessupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">1.00 per pound – 50,000 oranges supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">1.50 per pound – 70,000 oranges supplied.

  • 2.00perpound90,000orangessupplied.</span></p></li></ul><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">Afteranincreaseinsupply(S1):</span></p><ul><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">2.00 per pound – 90,000 oranges supplied.</span></p></li></ul><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">After an increase in supply (S₁):</span></p><ul><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">1.00 per pound – 65,000 oranges supplied.

  • 1.50perpound90,000orangessupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">1.50 per pound – 90,000 oranges supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">2.00 per pound – 115,000 oranges supplied.

After a decrease in supply (S₂):

  • 1.00perpound40,000orangessupplied.</span></p></li><li><p><spanstyle="color:rgb(0,0,0)">1.00 per pound – 40,000 oranges supplied.</span></p></li><li><p><span style="color: rgb(0, 0, 0)">1.50 per pound – 55,000 oranges supplied.

  • $2.00 per pound – 70,000 oranges supplied.

The supply curve shifts rightward (S₁) when supply increases and leftward (S₂) when supply decreases, demonstrating how external factors impact market supply.

FAQ

A shift in the supply curve directly impacts producer surplus, which is the difference between the price at which producers are willing to sell a good and the price they actually receive. When supply increases (rightward shift), the equilibrium price falls while the equilibrium quantity rises. Although producers receive a lower price per unit, they may still benefit if the increase in quantity sold outweighs the lower price, leading to a potential increase in total producer surplus. Conversely, when supply decreases (leftward shift), the equilibrium price rises, but the quantity sold decreases. This often results in a reduction in producer surplus, as fewer goods are sold and some producers may be unable to participate in the market. The extent of the change in producer surplus depends on the elasticity of demand and supply. If demand is inelastic, a price increase from a supply decrease may allow some producers to maintain or even increase their surplus.

In the short run, a shift in the supply curve alters the market equilibrium by changing the equilibrium price and quantity. A rightward shift (increase in supply) leads to a lower equilibrium price and a higher equilibrium quantity, whereas a leftward shift (decrease in supply) results in a higher price and a lower quantity. However, in the long run, these effects can be moderated by market adjustments. If supply increases, lower prices may encourage higher consumer demand, potentially stabilizing the market at a new equilibrium. If supply decreases, high prices might incentivize new firms to enter the market, increasing supply over time. Additionally, long-run supply shifts can be influenced by technological advancements, changes in production capacity, or market entry and exit. The extent of adjustment also depends on price elasticity; in markets with highly elastic supply, firms can respond quickly to price changes, making long-run equilibrium adjustments more rapid.

Government-imposed price controls, such as price floors and price ceilings, can distort the effects of supply shifts. A price floor, which sets a minimum legal price above equilibrium (e.g., minimum wage laws), can lead to a surplus when supply increases. For instance, if agricultural subsidies increase the supply of wheat while a price floor is in place, excess wheat may go unsold, requiring government intervention to purchase the surplus. Conversely, if supply decreases under a price floor, producers benefit from higher prices, but consumers may struggle with affordability. A price ceiling, which sets a maximum legal price below equilibrium (e.g., rent control), can create shortages when supply decreases. If a natural disaster reduces housing supply while a rent ceiling exists, fewer apartments will be available at the legal price, exacerbating the housing crisis. In both cases, price controls prevent the market from reaching its natural equilibrium, leading to inefficiencies such as surpluses, shortages, and black markets.

A supply shock is a sudden and unexpected event that drastically affects supply, often in the short term. Examples include natural disasters, wars, or major technological failures. Supply shocks can either be negative (reducing supply) or positive (increasing supply). A negative supply shock, such as an oil embargo, shifts the supply curve leftward, raising prices and reducing quantity supplied, often leading to inflation and economic slowdowns. A positive supply shock, such as a breakthrough in agricultural technology, shifts the supply curve rightward, lowering prices and increasing output, often benefiting consumers and stimulating economic growth. In contrast, long-term supply shifts result from gradual changes in factors like labor force growth, technological advancements, or policy changes. While supply shocks often create short-term volatility, long-term supply shifts tend to lead to more stable adjustments in production, wages, and overall economic growth. Policymakers must distinguish between the two to implement effective interventions.

Producers' expectations about future prices significantly impact their current supply decisions. If suppliers anticipate that prices will rise in the future, they may decrease current supply by holding back inventory or delaying production to sell at a higher price later. For example, if oil producers expect crude oil prices to increase next month, they may reduce output now to maximize future profits. This short-term restriction shifts the supply curve leftward, raising current prices. Conversely, if producers expect prices to fall in the future, they may increase current supply to sell as much as possible before prices drop. For instance, if farmers anticipate lower corn prices next season due to favorable weather forecasts, they may rush to sell their current harvest, shifting the supply curve rightward. The degree to which expectations affect supply depends on the storability of the good; durable goods and commodities with long shelf lives are more affected than perishable goods.

Practice Questions

A technological advancement in the production of electric vehicles leads to a reduction in manufacturing costs. Using a correctly labeled graph, explain how this change affects the supply curve for electric vehicles.

A technological advancement that reduces manufacturing costs increases the supply of electric vehicles. The supply curve shifts rightward because producers can now produce more vehicles at each price level. On a correctly labeled graph, the original supply curve (S₀) shifts to the right to a new position (S₁), showing an increase in quantity supplied at all prices. This shift occurs because lower production costs make production more profitable, incentivizing firms to supply more. The new equilibrium shows a lower price and a higher quantity of electric vehicles in the market.

Suppose a major hurricane destroys a significant portion of Florida's orange groves. Explain how this event affects the supply of oranges and illustrate the change using a supply curve diagram.

The destruction of Florida’s orange groves reduces the supply of oranges, shifting the supply curve leftward. On a correctly labeled graph, the original supply curve (S₀) moves left to a new position (S₂), representing a decrease in supply at all price levels. This shift occurs because fewer oranges are available for sale, increasing production costs for suppliers. As a result, the equilibrium price rises, and the equilibrium quantity falls. Consumers face higher prices due to the reduced supply, while producers must adjust their production to account for the limited availability of oranges.

Hire a tutor

Please fill out the form and we'll find a tutor for you.

1/2
Your details
Alternatively contact us via
WhatsApp, Phone Call, or Email